Post-WPI, Subbarao’s music may be more Baba Sehgal than Ilaiyaraaja


As I sit down to write this it is a rather cloudy, dull and insipid morning in Mumbai. An old Tamil number Vaa Vennila composed by the music maestro Ilaiyaraaja and sung by S P Balasubrahmanyam and S Janaki, is playing in the background. I happened to discover this song a few days back, quite by chance, and it has been playing nonstop on my laptop since then. It’s the most melodious composition that I have heard in a long-long time.
Dear Reader, before you start breaking your head over why am I talking about an old Ilaiyaraaja number, when the headline clearly tells you that I should be talking about other things, allow me to explain.
For a music director to be able to create melody a lot of things need to come together. First and foremost the tune has to be good. On top of that the musicians have to be able to flesh out the tune in a way that the music director had originally envisaged it. The lyrics need to make sense. The singers need to get the right emotion into the song and of course not be out of tune. The director of the movie needs to have the ability to recognize a good song when he hears one and not fiddle around with it. And so on.
The point I am trying to make is that “melody” cannot be created in isolation. A lot of things need to come together to create a melodious song and to have an individual born and brought in erstwhile Bihar of Kashmiri Pandit parents, who does not speak a word of Tamil (and not much Kashmiri either), humming it nearly 26 years after it was first released.
What is true about Ilaiyaraaja’s ability to create melody is also true about the ability of Duvvuri Subbarao, the governor of the Reserve Bank of India(RBI), to influence the Indian economy and take it in the direction where everyone wants him to.
The inflation number
The wholesale price index (WPI) inflation number for the month of June 2012 was released sometime back. The inflation has fallen to 7.25% against 7.55% in the month of May. The number has come in much lower than what the analysts and the economists were expecting it to be.
This is likely to lead to calls for the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) RBI to cut the repo rate.
The first quarter review of the monetary policy of the RBI is scheduled on July 31,2012. Industrialists, economists and analysts would want the RBI to cut the repo rate on this day. The repo rate is the interest rate at which RBI lends to the banks.
The first quarter review of the monetary policy is scheduled on July 31,2012. Industrialists, economists and analysts want the RBI to cut the repo rate on this day. The repo rate is the interest rate at which RBI lends to the banks.
So what is the idea behind this? When the RBI cuts the repo rate it is trying to send out a signal to that it expects the interest rates to come down in the months to come. If the banks think that the signal by the RBI is credible enough then they lower the interest rate they pay on their deposits. They also lower the interest rates they charge on their long term loans like home loans, car loans and loans to businesses. With people as well as businesses borrowing and spending more it is expected that the slowing economic growth will be revived.
That’s how things are expected to work in theory. But economic theory and practice do not always go together. The trouble is that even if the RBI cut the repo rate right now, the credibility of the signal would be under doubt, and banks wouldn’t cut interest rates. This is primarily because like Ilaiyaaraja, Subbarao and the RBI also do not work in isolation.
More loans than deposits
The incremental credit deposit ratio of the banks in the six month period between December 30,2011 and June 29,2012, has been 108%. What this means that during this period for every Rs 100 that banks have borrowed by raising deposits, they have loaned out Rs 108. Hence, banks have not been able to match their deposits to loans. They have been funding their loans out of deposits they had raised in periods previous to the six month period considered here. Given the shortage of deposits that banks are facing it doesn’t make sense for them to cut the interest rates on their deposits, even if the RBI were to go ahead and cut the repo rate. And if they can’t cut interest rates on their deposits there is no way the banks are going to cut interest rates on their loans. But why are banks facing a shortage of deposits?
The oil subsidy for this year is already over
The budget for the year 2012-2013 had made a provision of Rs 43,580 crore for oil subsidies. This provision is made to compensate the oil marketing companies (OMCs) Indian Oil Corporation, Bharat Petroleum and Hindustan Petroleum, for selling diesel, kerosene and LPG at a loss. Four months into the financial year the government has already run out of this money. The government has compensated the OMCs to the extent of Rs 38,500 crore for products at a loss in the last financial year (i.e. the period between April 1, 2011 and March 31,2012). This payment was made in this financial year and hence has been adjusted against the Rs 43,580 crore provisioned against oil subsidies in the budget for the current financial year.
The OMCs continue to sell these products at a loss. In the month of April 2012 they lost around Rs 17,000 crore by selling diesel, kerosene and LPG at a loss. In the last financial year the government compensated 60% of this loss. The remaining loss the government forced the oil producing companies like ONGC and Oil India Ltd, to compensate. So using the rate of 60%, the government would have to compensate around Rs 10,200 crore for the losses faced by the OMCs in the month of April. Add this to the Rs 38,500 crore of payment that has already been made, we end up with Rs 48,700crore. This is more than the Rs 43,580 crore that had been budgeted for.
The OMCs continue to lose money
The losses made by OMCs have come down since the beginning of the year. In April, the OMCs were losing Rs 563crore per day. A recent estimate made by ICICI Securities puts the number at Rs 355crore per day. At this rate the companies will lose around Rs 130,000 crore by the end of the year. Even if oil prices were to continue to fall the companies will continue losing substantial amount of money.
All this will mean an increase in expenditure for the government as it would have to compensate these companies to help them continue their operations and prevent them from going bust. An increase in expenditure would mean an increase in the fiscal deficit. Fiscal deficit is the difference between what the government spends and what it earns. The fiscal deficit for the current year has been budgeted to be at Rs 5,13,590 crore. It is highly unlikely that the government will be able to meet this target, given the continued losses faced by the OMCs.
Further borrowing from the government would mean that the pool of savings from which banks and other financial institutions can borrow will come down. This means that to banks will have to continue offering higher interest rates on their fixed deposits and hence keep charging higher interest rates on their loans.
High inflation
The consumer price index (CPI) inflation for the month of May stood at 10.36%, higher than the 10.26% in April. This is likely to go up even further in the days to come. The WPI inflation coming for the month of June has come in at xx%. And this is likely to push the CPI also in the days to come. CPI inflation will be pushed further given that the government increased the minimum support price on khareef crops from anywhere between 15-53% sometime back. These are crops which are typically sown around this time of the year for harvesting after the rains (i.e. September-October). The MSP for paddy (rice) has been increased from Rs 1,080 per quintal to Rs 1,250 per quintal. Other major products like bajra, ragi, jowar, soybean, urad, cotton etc, have seen similar increases. Also, after dramatically increasing prices for khareef crops, the government will have to follow up the same for rabi crops like wheat. Rabi crops are planted in the autumn season and harvested in winter. This will further fuel food inflation. Food constitutes around 50% of the consumer price index in India. In this scenario of higher inflation it will be very difficult for the RBI to cut the repo rate. And even if it does cut interest rates it is not going to be of any help as has been explained above.
To conclude
The way out of this mess is rather simple. Oil subsidies need to be cut down. That is the only way the government can hope to control its fiscal deficit. If things keep going the way they are I wouldn’t be surprised if the fiscal deficit of the government even touches the vicinity of Rs 6,00,000 crore against the budgeted Rs 5,13,590 crore.
Only once the government gives enough indications that it is serious about controlling the fiscal deficit, will the market start taking the interest rate policy of the RBI seriously. Before that even if the RBI were to cut interest rates it wouldn’t have an impact.
For Duvvuri Subbarao to make melody like Ilaiyaraaja does a lot of things which are not under his control need to come together. Ilaiyaraaja has control over the people he works with. He can tell his musicians what to play. He can ask his singers to sing in a certain way. He can ask his lyric writer to write a certain kind of song. And so on. Subbarao does not have the same control over the other players in the economy.
So in the meanwhile it is safe to say that try he might as much to make melody like Ilaiyaraaja, chances are he is likely to come up a song Baba Sehgal once made. It was called “Main Bhi Maddona”. For those who have heard the song will know that melody has never been “murdered” more.
(The article originally appeared on www.firstpost.com on July 16,2012. http://www.firstpost.com/economy/post-wpi-subbaraos-music-may-be-more-baba-sehgal-than-ilaiyaraaja-378448.html)
Vivek Kaul is a writer and can be reached at [email protected]

Should India fear Wal-Mart – the bully of Bentonville?


Vivek Kaul

Does the American president Barack Obama have the foot-in-the-mouth disease or is India just overreacting? In an interview to PTI Obama said “In too many sectors, such as retail, India limits or prohibits the foreign investment that is necessary to create jobs in both our countries, and which is necessary for India to continue to grow.” He also cited concerns over the deteriorating investment climate in India and endorsed another ‘wave’ of economic reforms.
Predictably this has led to a series of terse reactions from across the political spectrum in India. Indian politicians have gotten together and asked Obama to mind his own business. “If Obama wants FDI in retail and India does not want, then it won’t come just because he is demanding it,” said former finance minister and senior BJP leader Yashwant Sinha. The left parties were equally critical of Obama’s statement.
Veerapa Moily, the minister for corporate affairs said “Certain international lobbies like Vodafone are spreading this kind of a story and Obama was not properly informed about the things that are happening, particularly when India’s economic fundamentals are strong.” Moily clearly wasn’t joking. The corporates were also quick to criticise Obama’s statement.
But for a moment let’s keep aside the fact that India does not need any advice from the President of the biggest economy in the world and try and understand Obama’s statement in a little more detail.
What did Obama essentially mean by what he said? He was basically pitching for Wal-Mart, the biggest retailer in the world, to be allowed to do business in India. Wal-Mart is headquartered out of Bentonville in the American state of Arkansas. It currently has a marginal presence in India through a joint venture with Bharti.
Such is the fear of Wal-Mart entering India and destroying other businesses both small and large, that politicians from across the political spectrum have used it as an excuse for not allowing foreign direct investment in the retail sector in India. This fear comes from the Wal-Mart experience in the United States.
As Anthony Bianco writes in The Bully of Bentonville – How the High Cost of Wal-Mart’s Everyday Low Prices is Hurting America “It (Wal-Mart) grows by wrestling businesses away from other retailers large and small. In hundreds of towns and cities, Wal-Mart’s entry put ailing …shopping districts into intensive care and then ripped out the life-support-system.”
But that’s just one part of the story. The question to ask here is, whether what is true for America is also true for the rest of the world? And the answer is no.
Pankaj Ghemawat, who has the distinction of becoming the youngest full professor at the Harvard Business School, in his book Redefining Global Strategy, points out a very interesting story. “When CEO Lee Scott (who was the CEO of Wal-Mart from 2000 to 2009) was asked a few years ago about why he thought Wal-Mart could expand successfully overseas, his response was that naysayers had also questioned the company’s ability to move successfully from its home state of Arkansas to Alabama…such trivialisation of international differences greases the rails for competing exactly the same way overseas at home. This has turned out to be a recipe for losing money in markets very different from the United States: as the former head of the company’s German operations, now shut down, plaintively observed, “We didn’t realise that pillowcases are a different size in Germany.””
Given this the countries that Wal-Mart has achieved success in are countries which are the closest to the United States. As Ghemawat writes “Unsurprisingly, the foreign markets in which Wal-Mart has achieved profitability-Canada, Mexico and the United Kingdom are the ones culturally, administratively and geographically closest to the United States.”
Wal-Mart and other big retailers have had a tough time in emerging markets. As Rajiv Lal, a professor at the Harvard Business School told me in an interview I did for the Daily News and Analysis(DNA) “There is not even a single emerging market that I know where a foreign entrant is the number one retailer. In Brazil it is Pão de Açúcar, in China you have the local Beijing Bailian. In most markets even when there are foreign entrants the dominant retailer in the organised sector is still the local retailer.”
And there are several reasons for the same. The local retailers are very price competitive. “If Wal-Mart is operating in Brazil there is nothing that Wal-Mart can do in Brazil that the local Brazilian guy cannot do. If you want to procure supplies from China, you can procure supplies from China as much as Wal-Mart can procure supplies,” said Lal.
Also the local guys understand the market better. This is because they have a better understanding of the customers. “On top of that they have local merchants that they know they can source from and Wal-Mart may not,” said Lal.
The other big fear about the likes of Wal-Mart being allowed into India is that it will destroy the business of the local kirana store. This is a highly specious argument at best because it is not easy to compete with kirana stores. As Lal explained to me “Just because you are a big guy with a lot of money, it doesn’t mean that you can compete. Kirana stores have a lot of benefits that established retailers don’t have. First of all location. What rents do they pay versus what established companies have to pay? Employees, same story. On the consumer side they can deliver services, in terms of somebody calls them and asks can you deliver six eggs? The guy runs and delivers six eggs. That’s not something that the big established firms can provide.”
A Wal-Mart in the US is typically established outside the city where rents are low. But such a strategy may not work in India. “It’s not easy to open a 150,000 square feet store in India. That kind of space is not available. They can’t open these stores 50 miles away from where the population lives. People in India don’t have the conveyance to go and buy bulk goods, bring it and store it. They don’t have the conveyance and they don’t have the big houses. So it doesn’t work,” explained Lal.
The kirana stores also provide goods on interest free credit to their customers something that no big retailer can afford to do. Also as the economy grows the chances are that the kirana stores will grow faster than big retailers. “So think about in five years, where will organised retailing be as a market share. Maybe it’s less than 1% now, and maybe it will become 3% or 5% of total retailing. It will not be more than that. In five years organised retail grows from one percent to five percent, the economy would have grown by another 50 percent. If they grow from one to five percent and the economy grows by 50%, virtually it means that the number of kirana stores and mom and pop stores are actually growing. They are not reducing by any means,” said Lal.
Allowing foreign investment in the retail sector is also expected to bring down food inflation. As Satish Y Deodhar writes in Day to Day Economics “Allowing private players – including multi-brand retailers who bring in foreign direct investment – to deal in retail and wholesale markets will reduce trader margins. An empirical study on domestic and imported apples sold in India shows that there are a number of middlemen in the farm-to-finger supply chain: out of the final rupee spent by a consumer on apples, about 50 percent goes for trader margins…More competition through private players will reduce the margins for the middlemen and lower the prices for consumers.”
Allowing foreign retailers into India is thus likely to bring down food inflation. Also as explained earlier the kirana store has not much to fear from the likes of Wal-Mart and other foreign retailers. But the same cannot be said about the companies which are the organised retail sector. Wal-Mart does take time to get its act right, but eventually it does. As Lal put it “The people who should be more afraid should be people who are in the organised retailing sector and not the mom and pop stores.”
And that’s where the real story about all the opposition in allowing foreign retailers entering the country, might lie.
(The article originally appeared on www.firstpost.com on July 16,2012. http://www.firstpost.com/business/should-india-fear-wal-mart-the-bully-of-bentonville-378330.html)
(Vivek Kaul is a writer and can be reached at [email protected])

Of fiscal deficit, Manmohan Singh and a prayer to god


Vivek Kaul

India is country that lives on hope, gods and pipedreams. The Prime Minister Manmohan Singh is no different when it comes to this. In a recent interview after taking over as the finance minister of the country he said he was focusing on controlling the fiscal deficit through a series of measures that the officials were working on.
He did not explain what these measures were. But with things as they stand now, it is next to impossible for the government to control the fiscal deficit and the PM can just hope for the best.
Fiscal deficit is the difference between what the government earns and spends. For the financial year 2012-2013 (from April 1, 2012 to March 31, 2013) this number is expected to be at Rs 5,13,590 crore. The government finances the deficit by borrowing money or taking on debt as it is technically referred to as.
There are several reasons why the fiscal deficit is likely to turn out to be higher than the projected number. Let’s start with oil subsidies. Oil subsidies for the year have been budgeted at Rs 43,580crore. The government has more or less run out of this money. It has paid Rs 38,500 crore to oil marketing companies (OMCs) like Indian Oil Corporation, Bharat Petroleum and Hindustan Petroleum for selling diesel, kerosene and LPG, at a loss during the last financial year. This payment was made only in the current financial year and hence has had to be adjusted against the oil subsidies budgeted for the current financial year.
This leaves only around Rs 5080 crore (Rs 43,580 crore – Rs 38,500crore) with the government for compensating the OMCs for the losses for the remaining part of the year.
International oil prices have come down since the beginning of April. Back then the OMCs were losing around Rs 563crore per day. A recent estimate made at the beginning of July by ICICI Securities puts this loss at Rs 355crore a day. Oil prices have fallen further by around 8% since this estimate was made. Adjusting for that the oil companies continue to lose around Rs 325crore per day or around Rs 10,000 crore per month. Hence the Rs 5080 crore that the government has remaining in its oil subsidy account would be over in a period of 15 days, at the current rate of losses.
Oil prices have fallen by 32% to $85 per barrel since the beginning of April. It’s is unlikely that the price will continue to fall given that at some stage the oil cartel, Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), will intervene and start cutting production to push up prices. Also, the threat of confrontation between Iran and the United States has been on for a while. Even a whiff of a crisis can push up oil prices. Iran is the second largest producer of oil in OPEC after Saudi Arabia. It has been trying to sell oil in currencies other than the US dollar for the past few years, much to the annoyance of the US.
So if the OMCs continue to lose money at the current rate, the projected losses for the year will be over Rs 120,000 crore. In 2011-2012 the government compensated around 60% of the losses. It got oil producing companies like ONGC and Oil India Ltd to pay the OMCs for the remaining losses. If the same ratio is followed in this financial year as well, it would mean an extra burden of around Rs 72,000 crore for the government (60% of Rs 1,20,000 crore). The fiscal deficit would go up by a similar amount.
Oil subsidies are the not the government’s only problem. On June 14, 2012, the government had approved the minimum support price (MSP) of rice to be increased by 16% from Rs 1250 per quintal from Rs 1080 per quintal. The Food Corporation of India buys rice from the farmers at the MSP. The food subsidy for the current financial year has been set at Rs 75,000 crore. Experts believe that this number is terribly under-provisioned given the various programmes of the government. Also with a significant increase in the MSP of rice the food subsidy is expected to cost the government around Rs 40,000 crore more from its current estimates. Even this number is likely to be beaten because after increasing the MSP of rice significantly, a similar price increase would have to be made for wheat during the coming months.
What does not help is that interest payments on all the money that the government has previously borrowed, comes to Rs 3,19,759 crore. Other than paying interest the government also needs to repay the past debt that is maturing. This amount comes to Rs 1,24,302 crore. Hence the cost of total debt servicing comes to Rs 4,44,061 crore or around 87% of the projected fiscal deficit of Rs 5,13,590 crore for the year. There is nothing that Manmohan Singh and the government can do to control this.
If all these problems were not enough the monsoon till now has been 23% deficient. This impacts the purchasing power of “rural” India and means lower sales of cars, bikes, white goods and fast moving consumer products in rural India, leading to a lower collection of indirect tax for the government. Lower taxes can drive up the fiscal deficit further.
So what is the way out? The subsidy on various oil products needs to be brought down. That’s the only solution that Manmohan Singh led government has to this problem. But the question is will they bite the bullet and make some tough decisions? From the past record it can be safely said, the answer is no. Given these reasons hoping to control the fiscal deficit remains a distant pipe dream.
Hence it’s time for Manmohan Singh to do what most Indians do when they are stretched and stressed. Pray to god. And hope for the best.
(The article originally appeared in the Asian Age/Deccan Chronicle on July 16,2012. http://www.deccanchronicle.com/editorial/dc-comment/fiscal-deficit-and-prayer-god-905)
(Vivek Kaul is a writer and can be reached at [email protected])

People prefer 50% free to 33% lower price…


Here is a question. You invested your hard earned money in stocks. Your investments rose in value by 100%. Then things turned around and stock prices fell by 50%. How much money did you gain in the end? Before you jump up and say 50%, just hold on. You have ended up where you started. Let’s say you invested Rs 1 lakh to start with. A 100% gain on that meant that now your investment is worth Rs 2 lakh. A 50% loss on this meant that you were back at Rs 1 lakh. A 50% loss had wiped out a 100% gain. “People are not very good at performing arithmetic with complex forms such as logarithms, fractions, probability and percentages, because, for evolutionary reasons, the human brain has not evolved to perform these functions,” says Akshay R. Rao who holds the General Mills Chair in Marketing at the Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota. In recent research which has received widespread international attention, Rao and his colleagues found that shoppers prefer getting something extra free to getting something cheaper. This happens because of their inability at handling percentages. Rao talks about this and more in an interview with Vivek Kaul.
In recent research you found that “Shoppers prefer getting something extra free to getting something cheaper.” How did you come to that conclusion?
Our research examined the phenomenon of bonus packs in which the consumer gets a larger quantity for the same price. We contrast this offer with a standard price discount, where the consumer gets the same quantity for a lower price. Imagine that I am selling coffee beans, and I offer you 100 beans for Rs. 100 on a normal day. Then, one day, I offer you a 33% discount, so you receive 100 beans for Rs. 67. On another day, I offer you 50% extra (or free). You now get 150 beans for Rs. 100. But, I impose no limit on how many or how few coffee beans you can buy, on either day. So, on the day in which I offer 50% extra, you could quite easily have bought 100 beans for Rs. 67! Yet, most people prefer 50% more to a 33% lower price, even though the two options are economically equivalent! In fact, we find that when we offer 33% more and a 33% price discount (which is economically superior), people are indifferent.
Can you give us an example?
In India, particularly for products that are sold in bulk (such as dal, rice, cooking oil etc.) in the unorganized retail market, this tendency on the part of consumers to prefer free products is likely to be successfully employed by the retailer. In our research, we were able to increase sales of an inexpensive consumer packaged good by over 70% in a retail store, when we employed the extra/free bonus pack format relative to the price reduction format.
What sort of experiment did you carry out?
As I mentioned above, we conducted one experiment in a retail store, in which we varied the promotion format for one product (hand lotion) each week. All the other products in the store were not promoted, providing us a control for comparison. We measured sales volume during each of the weeks to compare consumer response to format variation, and found, as predicted, that offering a quantity increment yielded substantially higher sales than offering a price discount that was economically equivalent. We followed up this naturalistic study with a survey of adult consumers in a shopping mall, asking them to express their preference for options that were either reduced in price or featured an increase in quantity. We also asked our respondents to respond to some simple maths questions, to assess their computational skills. Again, as we expected, we found that those with better maths skills did not display this error, while those with poor maths skills displayed the erroneous preference for quantity increments.
Finally, we also showed that the error occurs for harmful as well as beneficial changes — people prefer a quantity decrease of 33% relative to a price increase of 50%, though both are economically equivalent.
What do people behave in this way?
Essentially, we demonstrate that this occurs because of “base value neglect” when dealing with percentages, a phenomenon akin to “denominator neglect”, a term coined by the illustrious psychologist Paul Slovic. According to this human tendency, people are not very good at performing arithmetic with complex forms such as logarithms, fractions, probability and percentages, because, for evolutionary reasons, the human brain has not evolved to perform these functions. For existence and survival, to find food and avoid becoming prey, we are quite successful as a species if we operate as “frequentists”, that is number counters. Hence, people treat percentages as whole numbers and make predictable errors in computation.
Do companies already realize that shoppers prefer something extra free rather than getting something cheaper?
Companies intuitively use some of this logic, but I am not sure they have thought this through the way we have. (If they had, our paper would not have been novel and would probably not have been published!). However, now that our paper has been published and has received widespread attention in the business press, I expect that companies will start experimenting with our results to assess whether and when they can profitably employ our theory and findings.
You have in the past said “errors in peoples’ judgments of the net effect of multiple price discounts on the same product or on different products in a bundle have implications for a variety of marketing settings including advertising, promotion, pricing and public policy”. Can you explain this in detail to our readers?
A classic problem in numerical competence with regard to the processing of percentage information is how people process multiple percentages. Think of the following example which first appeared in The New York Times and was quoted in the bestselling book How To Lie With Statistics (Huff 1954, 111):
“The depression took a stiff wallop on the chin here today. Plumbers, plasterers, carpenters, painters and others affiliated with the Indianapolis Building Trades Unions were given a 5 percent increase in wages. That gave back to the men one-fourth of the 20 percent cut they took last winter.”
A little thought will show that the maths is wrong here. If the workers were making $100 at the beginning, and experienced a 20% cut, their wages had dropped to $80. A subsequent 5% increase constitutes $4, which is one-fifth, not one-fourth of the original wage cut! Even the venerable New York Times makes maths errors!
That was an interesting example!
Now, take this example to the marketplace. Imagine that a store offers a 20% off Diwali sale, and offers an additional 25% off on Diwali sweets. What is the total discount? It is not the sum of the two percentages (45%), it is actually, only 40%! But, people systematically ignore the base value and add up percentages as if they are whole numbers. The problem becomes even more interesting when there are gains and losses. Imagine if your stock portfolio goes up by 40% and then declines by 30%. You might think you are still better off from where you started, by 10%. But, you would be wrong — you are actually worse off by 2%!
So what are the practical applications of this?
The application of these errors in advertising, promotion and pricing should be obvious. Consumers can be tricked by stores into thinking an offer is better than it actually is. From a consumer welfare standpoint, this is obviously not a good thing. So, we suggest that, the scientific insight we offer can be used to improve consumer welfare, by the introduction of regulations to require purveyors of numerical information to present absolute as well as percentage information. Particularly with regard to consumer finance (credit card interest rates) or the petrol consumption improvement of a car, it is possible for consumers to be fooled by multiple percentage changes that appear beneficial, when they are in fact harmful.
In one of your articles you discuss a study which points out: a) price may exert a non-conscious influence on expectancies about product quality b) such expectancies may have an impact on actual product performance c) such expectancies can also be induced through non-price information such as advertising claims about product quality. Can you explain this in detail?
This was a fascinating study authored by Baba Shiv of the University of Iowa (now at Stanford) and his colleagues Dan Ariely and Ziv Carmon, about which I was invited to write a commentary. The essence of their research was as follows. Some people were given a drink that was claimed to enhance mental acuity. Half the people were told that the product was purchased at $1.89 while the other half were told that the product, priced at $1.89 was purchased at a discounted price of $.89. Then, after they had drunk the liquid, they were given puzzles to solve. The group that drank the full-priced product solved significantly more puzzles (9.1) than the group that drank the discounted product (7.7)! Seemingly, people who drank the discounted drink expected that it would be less efficacious at increasing their mental acuity, and performed relatively poorly on the puzzle solving task! Their expectations sub-consciously influenced actual product performance. This is a powerful demonstration of the price-quality effect, a phenomenon that I have studied extensively over the last 25 years.
What is the learning for marketers here?
The remarkable thing about this research is the power of the placebo (as the authors term it). This placebo effect suggests that the human brain can be fooled into performing because it expects to perform. The implicit argument is that in many instances, psychology may be more important than engineering, in product design. The obvious learning for marketers is that consumers are subject to many subtle influences that have an impact on their subjective experiences. They may not be entirely rational and the creative and astute marketer is able to identify and exploit opportunities to influence consumer behavior through clever marketing.
Car dealers frequently draw customers into their establishment with the promise of an attractive advertised deal. However, upon arrival, the car buyer discovers that the deal does not apply to the model he wishes to buy. Nonetheless, after a few minutes of consultation with a ‘‘sales manager,’’ the salesperson returns with the news that an exception has been made and the deal has been approved. The buyer is relieved. Why does the dealership not simply offer the deal on the buyer’s preferred model in the first place?
The answer to this question lies in the psychological impact of the consumer experiencing relief. It is rooted in the “Good news, bad news” sequence phenomenon. People generally prefer to end on a high note (there is a good reason that dessert comes at the end of a meal!), and prefer to get bad news first and good news later, rather than the other way around. So, imagine you are boarding an international flight and reach for your passport in your pocket. It’s not there. Panic ensues. You search frantically, and find it in your briefcase. You experience an immense sense of relief because of good news following bad; this sense of relief would not have been experienced had you found your passport when you first reached into your pocket. It turns out that, when you experience this relief, you are psychologically vulnerable. Your cognitive resources to process bad news has been depleted, so your tendency to be loss averse increases. So, when a car dealer tells you that your preferred deal is not available, and then subsequently tells you that it may still be available, you experience relief and your desire to accept the deal increases, because you don’t want to lose the car. You negotiate with less vigor and wind up accepting a deal that is less advantageous to you than if you had not been taken through the bad news, good news roller coaster in the first place.
Companies often indulge in price wars when more often than not they turn out to be a race to the bottom. So why do they do it in the first place?
The impulse to fight on price is driven by many factors, not least of which is that the price variable is easy to change. Remember how Usha used to advertise in the 1980s – their slogan was “Massive Price Cut!” Dropping price in response to a competitor’s price cut is easier, particularly in the short-run, than engaging in creative actions such as promoting benefits, emphasizing your brand’s trustworthiness, alerting consumers to the risk of purchasing low-priced options that may perform poorly, and so forth. In my research and consulting work with companies in the U. S., Europe and Asia, I have found that most managers have been taught and instinctively feel that price is the most potent weapon in the marketplace. Therefore, it becomes the weapon of first resort — it is easy, available and often measurable (through changes in market share).
One sector that has been completely destroyed over the years because of price wars is the airline sector. But they still seem to have not got the point. How do you explain that?
In the year 1992, following a recession, there was a mad scramble in the airline industry in the U. S. to acquire market share. The easiest way to do so was to cut prices. And, it worked. Leisure travel increased that summer, revenues went up, but profits declined. Many experts have analyzed this continuous emphasis on price in the airline industry. At the present time, thanks to the internet and travel sites that routinely search for low-priced options, consumers have been taught by the industry to engage in price-comparison shopping. This is a phenomenon that is here to stay. Airlines have employed other means to enhance loyalty and revenue without suffering on price, through frequent flyer programs, through additional fees (such as baggage fees), but the fact remains that coach/economy travel is much less profitable than business and first class travel, particularly on international routes. Now, the managerial mindset is that price is the principal means of attracting and retaining customers.
You also write that “Managers can localize a price war to a limited theater of operation – and cut down the opportunities for the war to spill into other markets”. How do they go about doing that?
Price wars need not be global. They can be limited geographically, or to certain segments, or to certain product categories, at certain times, and so forth. Smart companies realize this. Returning to the airline industry, when a low price competitor enters a market, it offers inexpensive flights to a limited set of locations, and at certain times. The incumbent would be smart to cut prices on flights that cater to those destinations and at those times, at which the low-price competitor operates. It is not necessary to cut prices across the board. This is what Northwest Airlines did when a small rival — Sun Country — entered the market. To counter Sun Country, Northwest dropped its fares on the Minneapolis-Boston route, on flights that operated between 7:10 am and 11:10 am. That was the time at which Sun Country operated its Minneapolis – Boston flight.
Any other example?
Or, consider another creative strategy that is based on an intimate understanding of consumer price sensitivity. 3M used to make diskettes. It faced a new low-priced competitor — a Korean brand called Kao — and was faced with the prospect of a price war. Instead of dropping the price on 3M diskettes, it launched a “flanking brand” called Highland, at a low price to match Kao. Now, price sensitive customers had the choice of Highland and Kao, while quality sensitive customers stayed with 3M. This was a more profitable strategy than simply dropping the price for 3M diskettes, even though the Highland diskettes came off the same shop floor! Simultaneously, 3M signaled to Kao its intent to protect its market, and Kao eventually withdrew.
The interview appeared in the Daily News and Analysis on July 16,2012.
(Interviewer Kaul is a writer and can be reached at [email protected])

Why the gutka ban in Maharashtra won’t work


Vivek Kaul

One of the things about having grown up in erstwhile Bihar was that I ended up with the habit of having paan now and then. For brief periods of time it would turn into an addiction and I needed my paan right after lunch.
Nearly 10 years back, while working in Hyderabad my paan-eating habit was at its peak. I went out for my afternoon paan right after a heavy lunch. On one such occasion, while I was waiting for the paanwallah to make my daily fix, someone came and stood next to me. In chaste Hyderabadi Hindi he asked the paanwallah“kya miyan unne rakhe kya?
The paanwallah, who till then was sitting cross-legged, quietly got down and suddenly put his hand next to his crotch. For a moment I was too shocked at the scene that was playing out in front of me. The paanwallah then quietly handed over something wrapped in polythene and was handed over a Rs 10 note in exchange.
Once the exchange was over I asked the paanwallahkya diya usko?
Gutka!” the paanwallah replied.
In March 2002, the state of Andhra Pradesh had banned the sale of gutka. But such was the addiction of the people that gutka never really stopped selling in the state, and the system simply went underground. You could buy gutka packets at almost any paan shop in Hyderabad.
The only thing that had changed was that the price had more than doubled. Everybody made more money in the process. The police turned a blind eye to this menace because they had bigger criminals to catch. And at the end of the day how many paanwallahs could they have put in jail? Also, while I have no concrete proof for this, I am sure that the local hawaldars must have been kept happy by passing them a share of the increased profits. The gutka manufactures pleaded ignorance by saying that the packets were being smuggled into Hyderabad and Andhra Pradesh from the other neighbouring states where the sales weren’t banned.
So everybody made more money in the process. The gutka consumer lost out because he had to pay a higher price for his addiction, but then he really didn’t mind. The government lost out on the taxes that would have come from official gutka sales.
The government’s reasoning in banning the sale of gutka was simple. The decision was made in the interest of public health. The loss in tax revenue for the government was thus secondary. Using similar logic the government of Maharashtra recently banned the sale of gutka in the state. While at face-level this might seem like the “right” thing to do, it doesn’t really work.
Gutka is also banned in Kerala, Madhya Pradesh, Bihar and Uttar Pradesh. Maharasthra has also banned pan masala, becoming the first state in India to do so.
Bans to stop people from consuming products that are injurious to their health have never really worked in this country. Manufacture, sale or consumption of alcohol has been banned in Gujarat since 1960. But as anyone who has lived in Gujarat long enough will tell you, sourcing any kind of alcoholic drink isn’t a problem. You just need to know the right person who can home-deliver it.
The charismatic NT Rama Rao implemented prohibition in 1994 after an anti-liquor movement spearheaded by women grew across the state. The men never really stopped drinking. Liquor continued to be available and was simply smuggled into the state from the neighbouring states.
N Chandrababu Naidu, son-in-law of NTR, became the Chief Minister in 1997. He revoked prohibition on the pretext that it was “not successful or feasible because of the leakages within the state and from across the borders”.
Haryana implemented prohibition in mid-1996 and lost out on Rs 1,200 crore of tax revenue during the period. The drinkers simply moved to drinking in neighbouring Delhi and Punjab during the period.
When states ban consumption of alcohol, or gutka for that matter, they are following what the Directive Principles of State Policy envisaged when the constitution of India was made. Article 47 of the Directive Principles of State Policy states, “The state shall endeavour to bring about prohibition of the use, except for medicinal purposes, of intoxicating drinks and of drugs which are injurious to health.”
But such bans have never really worked. The government doesn’t have the administrative machinery required to implement such bans. Also, leakages from neighbouring states ensures that the supply of the banned good never really stops, be it gutka, pan masala or alcohol for that matter. In fact, with more profits to be made the risk of smuggling becomes increasingly lucrative.
Given these reasons, the ban on gutka and pan masala in Maharashtra will have no real impact accept moving their sales underground. The consumer addicted to it will readily pay more for the product. The government will lose out on the tax revenue.
The only way to ensure that the ban works is to have a nationwide ban and systematically ensure that no gutka-pan masala is produced or sold in this country. But that again is easier said than done. A lot of state governments may not be ready to lose out on the revenue that the sales of these products brings in. Moreover, what is to stop its smuggling from Nepal or Bangladesh? It also raises the question: why stop at banning gutka-pan masala and alcohol. What about banning cigarettes and bidis as well?
(The article originally appeared on www.firstpost.com on July 13,2012. http://www.firstpost.com/india/why-the-gutka-ban-in-maharashtra-wont-work-376475.html)
Vivek Kaul is a writer and can be reached at [email protected]